Schumpeter, Intellectuals, and What We See Around Us

I stumbled across this passage from Joseph Schumpeter’s Capitalism, Socialism, and Democracy, it struck a chord, and I thought I’d pass it along.

One of the most important features of the later stages of capitalist civilization is the vigorous expansion of the educational apparatus and particularly of the facilities for higher education. This development was and is no less inevitable than the development of the largest-scale industrial unit,9 but, unlike the latter, it has been and is being fostered by public opinion and public authority so as to go much further than it would have done under its own steam. Whatever we may think of this from other standpoints and whatever the precise causation, there are several consequences that bear upon the size and attitude of the intellectual group.

First, inasmuch as higher education thus increases the supply of services in professional, quasi-professional and in the end all “whitecollar” lines beyond the point determined by cost-return considerations, it may create a particularly important case of sectional unemployment.

Second, along with or in place of such unemployment, it creates unsatisfactory conditions of employment—employment in substandard work or at wages below those of the better-paid manual workers.

Third, it may create unemployability of a particularly disconcerting type. The man who has gone through a college or university easily becomes psychically unemployable in manual occupations without necessarily acquiring employability in, say, professional work. His failure to do so may be due either to lack of natural ability—perfectly compatible with passing academic tests—or to inadequate teaching; and both cases will, absolutely and relatively, occur more frequently as ever larger numbers are drafted into higher education and as the required amount of teaching increases irrespective of how many teachers and scholars nature chooses to turn out. The results of neglecting this and of acting on the theory that schools, colleges and universities are just a matter of money, are too obvious to insist upon. Cases in which among a dozen applicants for a job, all formally qualified, there is not one who can fill it satisfactorily, are known to everyone who has anything to do with appointments—to everyone, that is, who is himself qualified to judge.

All those who are unemployed or unsatisfactorily employed or unemployable drift into the vocations in which standards are least definite or in which aptitudes and acquirements of a different order count. They swell the host of intellectuals in the strict sense of the term whose numbers hence increase disproportionately. They enter it in a thoroughly discontented frame of mind. Discontent breeds resentment. And it often rationalizes itself into that social criticism which as we have seen before is in any case the intellectual spectator’s typical attitude toward men, classes and institutions especially in a rationalist and utilitarian civilization. Well, here we have numbers; a well-defined group situation of proletarian hue; and a group interest shaping a group attitude that will much more realistically account for hostility to the capitalist order than could the theory—itself a rationalization in the psychological sense—according to which the intellectual’s righteous indignation about the wrongs of capitalism simply represents the logical inference from outrageous facts and which is no better than the theory of lovers that their feelings represent nothing but the logical inference from the virtues of the beloved. Moreover our theory also accounts for the fact that this hostility increases, instead of diminishing, with every achievement of capitalist evolution. Of course, the hostility of the intellectual group—amounting to moral disapproval of the capitalist order—is one thing, and the general hostile atmosphere which surrounds the capitalist engine is another thing. The latter is the really significant phenomenon; and it is not simply the product of the former but flows partly from independent sources, some of which have been mentioned before; so far as it does, it is raw material for the intellectual group to work on. There are give-and-take relations between the two which it would require more space to unravel than I can spare. The general contours of such an analysis are however sufficiently obvious and I think it safe to repeat that the role of the intellectual group consists primarily in stimulating, energizing, verbalizing and organizing this material and only secondarily in adding to it. Some particular aspects will illustrate the principle.

6. Capitalist evolution produces a labor movement which obviously is not the creation of the intellectual group. But it is not surprising that such an opportunity and the intellectual demiurge should find each other. Labor never craved intellectual leadership but intellectuals invaded labor politics. They had an important contribution to make: they verbalized the movement, supplied theories and slogans for it—class war is an excellent example—made it conscious of itself and in doing so changed its meaning. In solving this task from their own standpoint, they naturally radicalized it, eventually imparting a revolutionary bias to the most bourgeois trade-union practices, a bias most of the non-intellectual leaders at first greatly resented. But there was another reason for this.

Listening to the intellectual, the workman is almost invariably conscious of an impassable gulf if not of downright distrust. In order to get hold of him and to compete with non-intellectual leaders, the intellectual is driven to courses entirely unnecessary for the latter who can afford to frown. Having no genuine authority and feeling always in danger of being unceremoniously told to mind his own business, he must flatter, promise and incite, nurse left wings and scowling minorities, sponsor doubtful or submarginal cases, appeal to fringe ends, profess himself ready to obey—in short, behave toward the masses as his predecessors behaved first toward their ecclesiastical superiors, later toward princes and other individual patrons, still later toward the collective master of bourgeois complexion. Thus, though intellectuals have not created the labor movement, they have yet worked it up into something that differs substantially from what it would be without them.

The social atmosphere, for the theory of which we have been gathering stones and mortar, explains why public policy grows more and more hostile to capitalist interests, eventually so much so as to refuse on principle to take account of the requirements of the capitalist engine and to become a serious impediment to its functioning. The intellectual group’s activities have however a relation to anti-capitalist policies that is more direct than what is implied in their share in verbalizing them. Intellectuals rarely enter professional politics and still more rarely conquer responsible office. But they staff political bureaus, write party pamphlets and speeches, act as secretaries and advisers, make the individual politician’s newspaper reputation which, though it is not everything, few men can afford to neglect.

In doing these things they to some extent impress their mentality on almost everything that is being done. The actual influence exerted varies greatly with the state of the political game from mere formulation to making a measure politically possible or impossible. But there is always plenty of scope for it. When we say that individual politicians and parties are exponents of class interests we are at best emphasizing one-half of the truth. The other half, just as important if not more so, comes into view when we consider that politics is a profession which evolves interests of its own—interests that may clash with as well as conform to the interests of the groups that a man or party “represents.”

Individual and party opinion is, more than anything else, sensitive to those factors in the political situation that directly affect the career or the standing of the individual or party. Some of these are controlled by the intellectual group in much the same sense as is the moral code of an epoch that exalts the cause of some interests and puts the cause of others tacitly out of court.

Finally, that social atmosphere or code of values affects not only policies—the spirit of legislation—but also administrative practice. But again there is also a more direct relation between the intellectual group and bureaucracy. The bureaucracies of Europe are of pre- and extra-capitalist origin. However much they may have changed in composition as the centuries rolled on, they never identified themselves wholly with the bourgeoisie, its interests or its scheme of values, and never saw much more in it than an asset to be managed in the interest of the monarch or of the nation. Except for inhibitions due to professional training and experience, they are therefore open to conversion by the modern intellectual with whom, through a similar education, they have much in common, while the tinge of gentility that in many cases used to raise a barrier has been fading away from the modern civil servant during the last decades. Moreover, in times of rapid expansion of the sphere of public administration, much of the additional personnel required has to be taken directly from the intellectual group—witness this country.

As a counterpoint, a sort of companion piece, see this analysis of the “Occupy” movement by Kenneth Anderson:

The OWS protestors are a revolt — a shrill, cri-de-coeur wail at the betrayal of class solidarity — of the lower tier New Class against the upper tier New Class. It was, after all, the upper tier New Class, the private-public finance consortium, that created the student loan business and inflated the bubble in which these lower tier would-be professionals borrowed the money. It’s a securitization machine, not so very different from the subprime mortgage machine. The asset bubble pops, but the upper tier New Class, having insulated itself and, as with subprime, having taken its cut upfront and passed the risk along, is still doing pretty well. It’s not populism versus the bankers so much as internecine warfare between two tiers of elites.

Read the whole thing.

8 comments… add one
  • jan Link

    It’s a wordy summation, but does make a cogent case for how interwoven the intellectual influence is with the worker and his path to ‘discontent’ with the capitalistic system.

    In comparing and contrasting the current OWS movement, specifically the student loan bubble, I totally agree with the similarities educational loans have with the sub-prime bubble/fiasco. Lessening qualifications, making it easier to attain goods or services, without taking into account unavoidable consequences down the road, creating an undifferentiated ‘bubble’ for everyone, will eventually burst under the pressure of such fiscal fantasies inherent in these short-sighted, enabling plans.

    When that happens the next stage is public resentment, finger-pointing and blaming the present-day fiscal or authoritarian ‘system’ on hand — that being, in today’s scenario, the evil capitalistic system. In a way, because the ‘blame’ is so broad-based and rather vacuous, it may explain why the OWS movement is having difficulty tying together a mission statement, even lacking clarity as to what it wants, and how it wants to change such a system it has deemed as failed them.

  • I have a question. When do you think “signalling” through a degree started? I know it started about 1985 in the start-up long-distance telephone company I worked for. To ascend into management one needed a degree. Not in IT or business, either. Something in French poetry would have sufficed.

  • sam Link

    Having no genuine authority and feeling always in danger of being unceremoniously told to mind his own business, he must flatter, promise and incite, nurse left wings and scowling minorities, sponsor doubtful or submarginal cases, appeal to fringe ends, profess himself ready to obey—in short, behave toward the masses as his predecessors behaved first toward their ecclesiastical superiors, later toward princes and other individual patrons, still later toward the collective master of bourgeois complexion. Thus, though intellectuals have not created the labor movement, they have yet worked it up into something that differs substantially from what it would be without them.

    Maybe it’s endemic to democratic forms of government. I’m reading Josiah Olber’s Mass and Elite in Democratic Athens, and Schumpter’s observations echo Olber’s description of the relationship between the educated elite of Athens and the largely uneducated idiotai and penetes whose collective word was law absolute in the state. Plus ça change….

  • PD Shaw Link

    Ms Gore: ’85 sounds right. I think the late 70s recession made people pesimistic about the prospects of the traditional manufacturing base for lifelong employment and drove people into higher education, as opposed to being attracted to new jobs. The surplus of college education encouraged employers (private and public) to begin restricting jobs on the basis of college degrees for convenience.

  • PD Shaw Link

    The last paragraph in the Schumpeter piece is the most interesting, particularly since he doesn’t consider lawyers to be intellectuals:

    “physicians or lawyers for instance are not intellectuals in the relevant sense unless they talk or write about subjects outside of their professional competence which no doubt they often do—
    particularly the lawyers. Yet there is a close connection between the
    intellectuals and the professions. For some professions—especially if we count in journalism—actually do belong almost wholly to the domain of the intellectual type; the members of all professions have the opportunity of becoming intellectuals; and many intellectuals take to some profession for a living.”

    I take it from this discussion that Dave’s dad, a lawyer who wrote for the newspaper on non-legal subjects, was an intellectual. Which I intend as a favorable remark. Though I think Schumpeter is suggesting that lawyers increasingly are required to administer the bureaucratic state even though this is outside of their professional competence.

  • I take it from this discussion that Dave’s dad, a lawyer who wrote for the newspaper on non-legal subjects, was an intellectual.

    No question about it. The third strike: he taught in a law school.

    One thing that should be remembered: Schumpeter was writing 70 years ago. I think a lot of what he was speculating about for the future is our present. In particular the professions have been nearly entirely absorbed by the intellectuals.

  • PD Shaw Link

    Some of his speculation seems a little Euro-centric to me. The first sentence I have the most problem with (vigorous expansion of higher education as “inevitable” consequence of capitalism)

    But that aside, it appears to me that this country is finding it very difficult to get 30% of the population to obtain a bachelor’s degree, the substantial increase in going to college appears to be met by declining graduation rates. That leaves a dynamic of I don’t know . . . over 70% of the population having their labor value devalued by government policies and pronouncements, over 20% being elevated, and less than 5% to cause trouble? I tend to think the market will correct, there will be fewer in some fields and more practical degree choices.

  • steve Link

    1) For predictions about late stage capitalism, read Marx.

    2) “That leaves a dynamic of I don’t know . . . over 70% of the population having their labor value devalued by government policies and pronouncements”

    Productivity has increased, but this has not translated into wage increases for most people. How is this caused by government? Arent most people paid by their employers?

    Steve

Leave a Comment