Everybody Likes Free Beer

There has been quite a bit of comment on this graph of rising healthcare costs from the Kaiser Family Foundation:

so I thought I’d put my oar in if only to question some of the other comments about it and raise some questions of my own.

Matt Yglesias titles his post on the graph “Consumers Like Buying Health Care Services”. That may or may not be true; I don’t believe you can make that determination from this chart. However, the remark does bring up some useful distinctions. “Buyers” are people who lay out money for something (just as “taxpayers” are people who actually pay taxes). In the United States and, I believe, all of the countries in that chart, consumers and buyers are two different groups of people, i.e. for a sizeable chunk of consumers their healthcare is heavily or entirely subsidized.

There are actually three components of any purchasing transaction: the buyer, the individual who makes the purchase decision, and the end consumer. They may be the same person; they may be three different people. So, for example, when I was very small (well over a half century ago) I may have eaten the chocolate Easter bunny (consumer) but my mom bought it (purchase decision) and my dad paid the bill (buyer).

Healthcare is a bit like that. Patients are, in general, neither the purchase decision-makers nor the buyers. Those roles are filled to some extent by physicians and insurance companies (and employers) or the government, respectively. Efforts at reducing costs follow that transactional process: they are targeted at unifying these roles and take different tacks depending on the ideological preferences of the proponent. So, for example, the Ryan plan is an attempt to make consumers more responsible for paying their own bills under the (in my belief) incorrect apprehension that if healthcare consumers and healthcare buyers are one and the same that the consumers will behave more prudently. However, it ignores that the role of consumer and decision-maker are also distinct.

The ACA via its review board strategy attempts to unify the decision-maker role with the buyer role. I believe it will be frustrated in that by healthcare consumers and by the sheer scope of the task: I don’t believe there are enough utterly unnecessary or provably futile procedures performed to achieve the necessary cost savings.

All that I think can be concluded from the graph are that a) healthcare costs for the selected countries in the graph are all rising at an unsustainably high pace and b) our healthcare costs are enormously higher than those of the other countries in the graph.

Now I’ve heard it argued that healthcare is a superior good and that as incomes rise more will be spent on healthcare. I think that argument is largely hooey for reasons largely along the lines of the transaction process I’ve outlined above: the consumers aren’t the only ones making the decision process and the consumers are insulated from both the decision-making and buying roles. It may be true that healthcare is a superior good; I just don’t think you can make that determination based on rising incomes and rising healthcare costs. The rising incomes and the rising consumption are on the part of overlapping but different groups. Is the theory of economics under which when party A says that party B must consume more X and it will be paid for by party C the theory of superior goods? I don’t think so.

Here’s my question: how much do the very rich (where most of the income growth in the United States has come from) spend on healthcare? Has their healthcare spending on themselves risen at the same rate as their incomes, at a lower rate, at the general rate of cost increases in healthcare, or not at all?

And the graph itself does bring up a question for me. Healthcare, as noted above, is hardly a market at all but some of its aspects are more market-driven than others. So, for example, GPs are more portable than medical specialists like, say, cardiologists or neurosurgeons. When physicians move from country to country it tends to be as GPs. And the median wages of GPs are more similar from country to country than, say, the median wages of cardiologists.

As is obvious from the chart the U. S. is the highest payer among the countries selected for it. To what extent does the price paid by the highest payer push up the prices for the other countries in the chart? Unless the answer is “not at all”, the perverse U. S. healthcare system is increasing healthcare costs everywhere.

Follow-up question: to what extent is that offset by the higher R&D costs that the U. S. is paying? What’s the relationship between costs and benefits?

6 comments… add one
  • Well Dave, I think you’re basically right about this chart. It’s sad to see that the usual suspects are using it as “proof” for their particular worldview and not considering deeper issues.

  • cfpete Link

    Dr. Schuler,
    This is not the graph you want.
    This is:
    http://www.kff.org/insurance/snapshot/images/OECDChart5_1.gif
    (Scroll down in the document you linked above.)
    The US could only hope to be like Switzerland.

    Which brings me to another problem.
    Why is this graph adjusted for ppp?
    “Healthcare” should be the poster child for non ppp adjustment.
    (That is, until we all fly to Asia for our hip replacements.)

    Would like to comment more on the ppp adjustment but have to go to a wedding of people I have never met.
    Hope we gave them a nice gift!
    Will comment later when the yelling stops.

  • After seeing this graph in a few places, I begin to wonder – how much of our health care cost inflation is driven by lawsuit avoidance treatment rather than rational decision making on the best course of action?

    I am by no means saying that we should eliminate malpractice suits, but one has to wonder the proportion of health care cost inflation that is due to not wanting to be accused of doing everything possible to save a life, even if “everything possible” isn’t rational.

  • how much of our health care cost inflation is driven by lawsuit avoidance treatment rather than rational decision making on the best course of action?

    I think it’s more precise to phrase it as “the way medicine is practiced today” rather than “lawsuit avoidance”. Standards of care require certain steps that may not be precisely the optimal and proven course of action.

  • I think that some of the things that started out as “lawsuit avoidance” became “standard care.” Having become standard practice, it isn’t clear that tort reform would actually change the procedures.

  • Is the theory of economics under which when party A says that party B must consume more X and it will be paid for by party C the theory of superior goods?

    Well that doesn’t make it a superior good, but that is kind of how insurance tends to work.

    Health care is probably a superior good in that the more money you have you might divert a growing percentage of your income to health care. If this is generally true, i.e. true across age groups, health status, etc., then it would probably be a superior good.

    In other words, the subsidies, lack of consumer knowledge, that the person having considerable input on the purchase decision and on the supply side as well (a.k.a. the doctor) probably can be most charitably defined as having a conflict of interest, totally open ended in terms of expenditures, and that the good in question might very well be a superior good is a recipe for out of control spending.

    In other words, car insurance works like you describe above, but getting my car fixed isn’t a superior good (most likely) hence and it isn’t subsidized (at least not to the same extent) so it is lacking at least two of the problems above. Same for most other types of insurance. Flood insurance works the same way (note I’m assuming you need to use the insurance–i.e. there has been a flood or your wrecked your care…or in the health care situation you have a medical condition).

    Also, many other forms of insurance have a defined payout. You wreck your car and the insurance company will spend up to a given amount of money to fix the car, or if fixing it is beyond the cost of the vehicle itself, pay what the value of the car was just before the accident. Health care on the other hand doesn’t have that either. In many cases it is open ended. If it costs $10,000, $100,000 or $1,000,000 spend it.

Leave a Comment