I think we can safely conclude that the editors of the Wall Street Journal very much support cutting taxes. They’ve got two editorials on the subject today. In the first editorial they point to the inadequacies of the present system:
Start with the fact that the GOP budget outline allows for a net tax cut of $1.5 trillion over a decade on a statically scored basis thanks to a deal brokered by Senators Pat Toomey and Bob Corker. Democrats and their media chorus are using that number to claim that reform will bust the budget and add to the federal debt. This comes with ill grace from people who cheered Barack Obama’s doubling of the national debt in eight years, but it’s also overwrought.
The actual budget hole is smaller than $1.5 trillion because the GOP budget is scored on a “current law†baseline. This assumes that tax breaks that are “current policy†will expire and more revenue will flow to Treasury. This is worth more than $400 billion over 10 years, which means the budget “hole†is closer to $1 trillion out of the $43 trillion the Congressional Budget Office projects in revenues over the next decade. In other words, this is a modest net tax cut even assuming no additional economic growth.
CBO’s estimates are inherently speculative because no one knows when the next recession might hit or what some future Congress might do. But CBO has typically underestimated the growth and revenue feedback from tax cuts. A classic example is the 2003 cut in the tax rate on capital gains. Dan Clifton of Strategas Research notes that in January 2004, eight months after the tax cut passed, CBO predicted $215 billion in capital-gains revenue through 2007. The actual figure? $377 billion. CBO underestimated economic growth and how much investors would cash in their gains.
CBO’s roughly $43 trillion revenue estimate also depends on a projection of average economic growth of 1.9% a year. But the U.S. economy has never grown that slowly for so long. CBO says that every 0.1% increase in GDP adds about $270 billion in revenue over 10 years. That means a mere four years at 3% growth—the U.S. historical norm—could fill a $1 trillion hole. An average growth rate of even 2.4% over the decade would more than fill the hole.
Nearby we reprint a letter from some of the country’s most distinguished economists making the case that the House and Senate reforms will significantly raise U.S. growth potential. The biggest boost comes from the reductions in the tax burden on capital, which should increase investment and thus growth.
One of the signers, Larry Lindsey, predicted in our pages this fall that economic growth under the GOP plan would accelerate to 3.2% for three to five years and then settle at 2.5%. The Tax Foundation predicts the Senate plan will produce more than $1 trillion in revenue, in part thanks to an investment catalyst from immediate capital expensing in the first year.
The left ignores all this and flogs as unrefutable whatever emerges from the Joint Committee on Taxation. But Joint Tax assumes the U.S. is a partially “closed†economy with little access to global markets. Its models assume that higher deficits will “crowd out†private borrowing and thus drive up interest rates and offset the growth impact of the tax cut. Yet a major goal of the tax reform is make the U.S. more competitive as a destination for foreign capital, and interest rates in a global capital market will be determined by far more than a modest increase in the U.S. budget deficit.
Another false charge from the left is that the GOP bills are merely a tax cut without any reform. But the bills eliminate trillions of dollars in loopholes, such as the state and local tax deduction. The House bill caps the mortgage-interest deduction at $500,000.
while the second piece outlines notions of how the run on effects of a tax cut in the form of an open letter to the Secretary of the Treasury signed by a list of economists and other worthies:
The present debate over tax reforms proposed by President Trump’s administration and embodied in bills that have passed the House of Representatives and the Senate Finance Committee has raised the basic question of whether the bills are “pro-growthâ€: Would the proposals raise current and future economic activity and generate federal tax revenue that would reduce the “static cost†of the reforms? This letter explains why we believe that the answer to these questions is “yes.â€
Economists generally think of fundamental tax reform as a set of tax changes that reduces tax distortions on productive activities (for example, business investment and work) and broadens the tax base to reduce tax differences among similarly situated businesses and individuals. Fundamental tax reform should also advance the objectives of fairness and simplification.
The quest for such fundamental tax reform has been pursued by policy makers and economists for decades. Examples include the Tax Reform Act of 1986, proposals for reducing the double taxation of corporate equity by the Treasury Department and the American Law Institute (enacted in part in 2003), the “Growth and Investment Plan†from President George W. Bush’s Advisory Panel on Federal Tax Reform, and arguments from President Obama’s administration to lower corporate tax rates. The proposals emerging from the House, Senate, and President Trump’s administration, fall squarely within this tradition.
Reducing Corporate Tax Rates, as Proposed, Will Increase Economic Activity
While the overall House and Senate tax plans contain numerous household and business provisions, we focus on the corporate tax changes, returning to other provisions before concluding. A key concept in this context is the “user cost of capital,†which essentially measures the expected cost to firms of making additional investments in equipment. A considerable body of economic research concludes that reductions in the user cost of capital raise output in the short and long run. Several of the proposals that have emerged in the current debate are key to lowering the user cost of capital. For example, expensing, which allows firms to deduct the full cost of investment at the time it is made, lowers the user cost of capital relative to depreciation over time. A lower corporate tax rate also lowers the user cost of capital, which not only induces U.S. firms to invest more, but also makes it more attractive for both U.S. and foreign multinational corporations to locate investment in the United States.
There is some uncertainty about just how much additional investment is induced by reductions in the cost of capital, but based on an extensive body of scholarly research, many economists believe that a 10% reduction in the cost of capital would lead to a 10% increase in the amount of investment. Simultaneously reducing the corporate tax rate to 20% and moving to immediate expensing of equipment and intangible investment would reduce the user cost by an average of 15%, which would increase the demand for capital by 15%. A conventional approach to economic modeling suggests that such an increase in the capital stock would raise the level of GDP in the long run by just over 4%. If achieved over a decade, the associated increase in the annual rate of GDP growth would be about 0.4% per year. Because the House and Senate bills contemplate expensing only for five years, the increase in capital accumulation would be less, and the gain in the long-run level of GDP would be just over 3%, or 0.3% per year for a decade.
Is this estimate of the growth effect realistic? According to one leading model using an alternative framework, the proposal would increase the U.S. capital stock by between 12% and 19%, which would raise the level of GDP in the long run by between 3% and 5%. Yet another model, this one used in the analysis of the “Growth and Investment Plan†in the 2005 President’s Advisory Panel on Federal Tax Reform, found that a business cash-flow tax with expensing and a corporate tax rate of 30% would yield a 20.4% increase in the capital stock in the long run and a 4.8% increase in GDP in the long run. More conservative estimates from the OECD suggest that corporate tax changes alone would raise long-run GDP by 2%. In short, there is a substantial body of research suggesting that fundamental tax reform of the type being proposed would have an important effect on long-run GDP. We view long-run effects of about 3% assuming five years of full expensing, and 4% assuming permanent full expensing, as reasonable estimates.
Another advantage of the corporate rate reduction embodied in the House and Senate Finance bills is that it would lead both U.S. and foreign firms to invest more in the United States. In addition, U.S. multinational firms would face a reduced incentive to shift profits abroad, which would raise federal revenue, all else equal.
In the foregoing analysis, we assumed a revenue-neutral corporate tax change. Deficit financing of part of a reduction in taxes increases federal debt and interest rates, all else equal. For the House and Senate Finance bills, this offset is likely to be modest, given that the United States operates in an international capital market, which means that the impact of changes in interest rates resulting from greater investment demand and government borrowing are likely to be relatively small.
Lowering Individual Tax Rates Also Offers Generally Positive Economic Effects
The House and Senate bills also contemplate a number of individual tax provisions that can affect economic activity and incomes. In recognition of the fact that non-corporate business income is substantial in the United States, both bills would reduce taxation of non-corporate business income and increase the amount of capital expensing allowed. While difficult to quantify, as the bills specify different effective tax rates, these provisions would increase investment and GDP above the level associated with the corporate tax changes discussed above. Also on the individual side, both the House and Senate bills reduce marginal tax rates on labor income for most taxpayers, increasing the reward for work. Increases in labor supply, in turn, increase taxable income and tax revenues. One should note, however, that some taxpayers would face increases in effective marginal tax rates because of base-broadening features of the bills, such as limits on the federal tax deductibility of state and local income taxes. On balance, though, we believe that the individual tax base broadening embodied in the proposals would enhance economic efficiency by confronting most households with lower marginal tax rates. In addition, fairness would be served by reducing differences in the tax treatment of individuals with similar incomes, and simplification by reducing the number of individuals who itemize for federal tax purposes.
Confirming a Pro-Growth Objective Is Important for the Path Forward
You have consistently stressed that the objective of tax reform should be to enhance prospects for increased economic growth and household incomes. We agree with this objective, which is consistent with the traditional norms of public finance going back to Adam Smith. We believe that the reforms embodied in the House and Senate Finance bills would achieve this objective. The increased growth, in turn, would lead to greater taxable income and federal tax revenues, which would reduce the static cost of lost federal tax revenue from the reform.
We hope these analytical points of support for the growth effects of tax plans being discussed are useful to you and to the Congress as you complete the important economic task of fundamental tax reform. We would be happy to discuss our conclusions with you at your convenience.
I’ve already outlined my views on our tax system multiple times. I think that at the very least we should cut the corporate income tax so the nominal rates fall within OECD norms, preferably abolishing it entirely, and add a tax rate above present brackets to make up the difference. A more complete overhaul would abolish both corporate and personal income tax in favor of a prebated VAT.
I wish the Democratic Congressional leadership would present their views in a more complete way. Democratic arguments against tax cuts have tended to center around fairness, something for which I never recall their giving a real definition. A head tax meets intuitive ideas of fairness. They’re enforceable but highly regressive. What’s called a “flat tax” (single tax bracket) also meets intuitive ideas of fairness but it, too, is regressive.
Consider this graph:

Clearly, the present system isn’t fair. The lowest 50% of income earners pay too little; the top 1% pay too much. In the light of that graph and their frequent complaints about fairness I think it’s incumbent on the Democratic leadership to define their idea of fairness.
I also want to know how they’ll meet our future spending commitments at the very low rate of economic growth that prevailed under the Obama Administration or, alternatively, how they’d encourage economic growth. I find it amusing that the very same people who complained that the Republicans had no alternative health care reform plan in 2010 do not fault the Democrats for having no credible economic plan now.
I’m skeptical of the Republican view. I don’t think that we can achieve the level of economic growth they foresee as long as we import as much as we do, so much of GDP is based on consumer spending, and domestic business investment is so low. I also see little in their plans which would change any of that.
When I say “it’s complicated”, that’s what I mean.
I think part of the issue for Democrats is that economically speaking they constitute a coalition of non-taxpayers and upper-class professionals. So the natural internal conversation is going to be about how tax cuts only favor those who pay taxes and the loudest criticism will be the removal of deductions for upper-class professionals (like for SALT).
The Bennet-Brown alternative tax cut more than tipples the child tax credit and makes it refundable, which would benefit non-taxpayers with children/dependents below the phase-out levels. I don’t know if that is good policy, but it seems like good politics.
That is my problem with both political parties. Party positions appear to be framed through one (or all) of three lenses: the purely political, sophistry, and stupidity.
When the Democratic leadership complains about tax cuts for the rich, is it purely political, sophistry, or stupidity? When half of the electorate pay no income tax of course tax cuts will be for the rich. Nobody else pays income taxes. If the complaint is about overall tax burden including FICA, FICA should be put on the table, too. I think that FICA should be abolished and SSRI paid out of the general fund, a view anathema to Republicans and Democrats alike.
Whether you think it’s good policy or not, the Bennet-Brown proposal isn’t tax reform. It’s welfare reform masked as tax reform. We need to start deciding whom we should subsidize and whom we shouldn’t. I’d like to see a consensus on eliminating subsidies more generally. They tend to benefit higher income earners.
Complaint from Jimbino in 3…2…1…
Well, the simplest solution would be to get rid of income inequalities in the range of 300-to-one.
How? We can raise nominal rates but that won’t necessarily increase effective rates.
IMO the closest we can come is to reverse the Clinton-era rule on executive compensation deductibility (I think that’s what started the big bump in income inequality).
You just have an economic system in which a small group of people don’t have the power to give themselves a disproportionate share of the nation’s income. It’s no different from not allowing one of your three children to award to themselves all three of the ice cream cones you buy.
You haven’t answered the question. Unless you’re trying to find a nice way to say “force”.
Will force actually get what you want? Or will it kill the goose who laid the golden eggs?
With children you start at birth teaching them that sharing is good. It doesn’t come naturally. They must be taught. Later is too late. Also with children teaching by example is one good approach. What are our leaders teaching by example?